Tuesday, 17 October 2023

PAST AS PRESENT--6 GLIMPSES OF A POSSIBLE HISTORY FROM BELOW: EARLY INDIA

 6  GLIMPSES OF A POSSIBLE HISTORY FROM BELOW: EARLY INDIA


The nineteenth century was the age of the grand edifices of historical explanation and theoretical construction. While some of these edifices still stand firm, others are tottering. Even those that still stand often require repair and renovation, sometimes of a structural kind, in the light of new knowledge and fresh theories. The refining of concepts and theories therefore becomes a necessary part of the historical exercise and is particularly incumbent on those who, as conscientious historians, use theoretical frameworks to formulate their initial hypotheses.

Among the early sub-periods, Vedic society has been described as tribal. The term ‘tribal’, which we have all used in the past, has rightly come in for some questioning. Whatever precision it may once have had seems to have become blurred, so perhaps we need either to redefine it or to use more exact terms for societies that we have so far described as tribal. 

In its precise meaning, ‘tribe’ refers to a community of people claiming descent from a common ancestor. In its application, however, it has been used to cover a variety of social and economic forms, not to mention racial and biological identities: and this tends to confuse the original meaning. 

Even as a convention it has lost much of its precision. The more recently preferred term, lineage, narrows the focus. Although the economic range remains, lineage does emphasize succession and descent with the implication that these are decisive in determining social status and control over economic resources. It also helps differentiate between chiefships—where lineage is a significant identity, and kingship—where power is concentrated and evokes a larger number of impersonal sanctions.

 The concept of vamsha (succession) carries a meaning similar to lineage and is central to Vedic society with its emphasis on succession even as a simulated lineage. Thus vamsha is used to mean a descent group among the rajanyas or kshatriyas, but is also used in the list of Upanishadic teachers where succession refers not to birth but to the passing on of knowledge.


Lineage becomes important in the structure of each varna, defined by permitted rules of marriage and kinship and by ranking in an order of status, the control over resources being implicit. The emergence of the four varnas is thus closely allied to the essentials of a society based on the central identity of lineage.

                In a stratified society the reinforcing of status is necessary. But where there is no recognized private property in land, and no effective state, such reinforcing has to be done by sanctions that often take a ritual or religious form. In the absence of taxation as a system of control in the Vedic period, sacrificial ritual functioned as the occasion for renewing the status of the yajamana, the patron who orders the sacrifice. Apart from its religious and social role, sacrificial ritual also had an economic function. It was the occasion when wealth that had been channeled to the yajamana was distributed by him in the form of gifts to the brahmana priests, and these strengthened their social rank and ensured them wealth. The ritual served to restrict the distribution of wealth to the brahmanas and the kshatriyas but at the same time prevented a substantial accumulation of wealth by either, for whatever came in the form of gifts and prestations from the lesser clans, the vish, to the ruling clans, the kshatriyas, was largely consumed in the ritual and only the remainder gifted to the brahmanas. Generosity being important to the office of the chief, wealth was not hoarded. This is a form of the economy of gift- exchange although the exchange is uneven: the priest receives the tangible gift whereas the patron can only claim the intangibility of status and spiritual merit on the completion of the ritual. The display, consumption and distribution of wealth at the major rituals such as the rajasuya and the ashvamedha, was in turn a stimulus to production, for the ritual was also seen as a communication with and sanction from the supernatural. Embedded in the sacrificial ritual therefore were important facets of the economy. This may be a partial explanation of why a major change in the state system accompanied by a peasant economy occurred initially in the mid-first millennium BC not in the western Ganga valley but in the adjoining area of the middle Ganga valley. This change was occasioned, not only by an increase in economic production and a greater social disparity but also by the fact that the prestation economy—of making gift offerings to a patron usually associated with a lineage-based society—became more and more marginal in the latter region, and in some areas was altogether absent.

Some scholars regard the term ‘peasant economy’ as an imprecise concept. However, it is of some use as a measurement of change. The label of ‘peasant’ has been applied to a variety of categories, some of which are dissimilar. The use of a single word as a portmanteau description confuses the categories and therefore a differentiation is necessary. Eric Wolf defines peasants as transferring their surplus to a ruler which surplus is then used to support the lifestyle of the ruler and the elite.’ This definition seems to me inadequate, for the important point is not merely the existence of a surplus but the mechanism by which it is transferred, and it is to this that I would relate the emergence of a peasant economy. That the recognition of an incipient peasant economy in various parts of India is significant to the study of social history hardly needs stressing since concomitant with this is also the establishing of particular kinds of state systems, variant forms of jatis and new religious and cultural idioms in the area. For the early period of Indian history the term peasant has been used to translate both the Rigvedic vish as well as the gahapati (this roughly translated as ‘peasant’ but more of this later) of Pali sources. But some distinction is called for. The Vedic vish was primarily a member of a clan although this did not preclude him from being a cultivator as well. The transferring of surpluses, in this case the voluntary prestations of the vish to the kshatriya, points to a stratified rather than an egalitarian society and the simile in the Veda of the kshatriya eating the vish like the deer eats the grain, would indicate greater pressures for larger gifts, prestations, offerings.

                But, the transfer was not invariably through an enforced system of taxation. In the absence of private ownership of land, the relationship of the vish to the kshatriya would have been less contrapuntal, with little need of an enforced collection of the surplus. The context of the references in the Vedas to bali, bhaga and shulka (the offering, the share, the value), terms used in later periods for taxes, suggest that at this time they were voluntary and random, although the randomness gradually changed to required offerings particularly at sacrificial ritualsHowever, the three major prerequisites governing a system of taxation—a contracted amount, collected at stipulated periods, by persons designated as tax collectors—are absent in the Vedic texts. The recognition of these prerequisites in the post-Vedic period and the collection of taxes from the cultivators by the State would seem decisive in registering the change from cultivators to peasants in which the existence of an economy based on peasant agriculture becomes clear.

The introduction of taxation presupposes the impersonal authority of the State and some degree of alienation of the cultivator from the authority to whom the surplus is given, unlike in the lineage-based society where gifts were given more informally although directly. Taxation reduced the quantity of gifts and became the more substantial part of what was taken from the peasant, but these prestations were not terminated. The sanction of the religious ritual becomes more marginal and that of the state more central, the change occurring gradually over time. The formation of the state is therefore tied into this change. For the cultivator

the change to land becoming property or a legal entity—whether his or of

someone else—and the pressures on cultivation, have to do not only with

subsistence but also with a provision for ensuring a surplus. This highlights the

difference between appropriation in the earlier system and exploitation in the

latter.

The Vedic vish was more a generalized label under which herding, cultivation

and minimal crafts adequate to a household were included. Such groups were

germane to the later peasant household. In effect, because the relationship with

the dominant kshatriyas was based on gifts rather than on taxes, these cultivators

would seem part of a lineage society in which their subservience to a dominant

group arose more out of the exigencies of kinship or the ordering of clans than

out of exploited labour, although the latter can be seen to increase in time.

A gradual mutation becomes evident from the frequent references in the Pali

sources to the gahapati. The existence of the gahapati focuses more sharply on

the presence of what might be called a peasant economy. But to translate

gahapati as peasant is to provide a mere slice of its total meaning. Derived from

grihapati, the head of the household, the gahapati included a range of meanings

such as the wealthy mahashala brahmanas addressed as gahapatis by the Buddha,

who had received as donations extensive, tax-free, arable land and is also used

for those who paid taxes—the wealthy landowners who cultivated their large

farms with the help of slaves and hired labourers (dasa-bhritaka).

Those at the lower end of the scale who either owned small plots of land or

were professional ploughmen are more often referred to as the kassakas, from

the Sanskrit word for cultivators, karshaka. The Arthashastra mentions tenants

as upavasa and also refers to another category, the shudra cultivators settled by

the state on cultivable or waste land on a different system of tenure from the

aforesaid: as also the range of cultivators employed on the state farms supervised

by the overseers of agriculture, the sitadhyaksha.

Gahapati, therefore, is perhaps better translated as a landowner who would

generally pay taxes to the state except when the land which he owned was a

religious benefice. The ownership of land and the payment of taxes demarcates

this period of the mid-first millennium BC as one in which a peasant economy


emerged. Traces of the lineage-based society continued in the marking of status

by varna and the performance, although by now of less economic significance,

of the sacrificial rituals.

That the gahapati was not even just a landowner but more a man of means is

supported by the fact that it was from the ranks of the gahapatis that there

emerged the setthis or the financiers. The two terms are often associated in the

literature of the period and this is further attested in the votive inscriptions

recording donations to the Buddhist sangha at stupa sites in central India and the

western and eastern Deccan from the late first millennium BC. Gahapati fathers

have setthi sons as well as the other way round. It would seem that gahapati

status was acquired through the practice of any respectable profession that

provided a decent income, although the most frequent references are to

landownership and commerce.

This is not to suggest that trade originated with the landowning groups but

rather that the commercialization of exchange was probably tied to the

emergence of the gahapati. In examining the origins of trade it is necessary to

define more clearly the nature of the exchange involved. Broadly, there are some

recognizable forms of exchange that can either develop into commercialized

exchange or supplement it. There is evidence of luxury goods exchanged by

ruling groups as a part of gift-exchange. Marriage alliances between kshatriya

families involved an exchange of gifts. Thus, when Bharata visits his maternal

Kekeya kinsmen, he returns with a variety of gifts, including horses. This is not

an exchange based on need but is a channel through which status and kinship is

confirmed. It may in addition lead to other forms of exchange.

The major royal sacrifices required tributes and gifts to be brought to the

yajamana which he then distributed at the end of the ritual. The description of

the rajasuya of Yudhisthira in the Mahabharata provides an interesting inventory

of valued items. Sacrificial rituals involved the gifting of cattle and possibly

some gold. Boastful poets added to this horses, chariots, and on occasion, dasis

(slave women), given to them by the victorious cattle-raiders whose prowess the

poets had praised. These gifts became part of a distribution and exchange of

wealth which in lineage-based societies formed the salient part of the wealth of

those who ruled, whereas in the change to an economy based on peasant

agriculture, they were merely a part of the wealth accumulated by the ruling

families and the more wealthy gahapatis.

Less spectacular but more essential was another form of exchange—that of

raw materials and commodities brought by itinerant groups such as smiths and

pastoralists. It has been argued that the itinerant metal-smiths formed a network


of connections between villages. Metal, particularly iron and iron objects were

items of regular trade. The role of pastoralists in forms of exchange and in

trading circuits is now gaining attention, particularly of those groups that had a

regular pattern of transhumance—moving from pastures at lower elevation to

those higher up in summer and returning in winter. Transactions that accompany

this circuit have been described as a vertical economy. Exchange through

sources of itinerant professionals was probably the starting point of the beat of

pedlars that remains a continuing feature of one level of exchange in India.

Yet another category is what might be called exchange between one

settlement and the next. This is a useful basis for plotting the gradual diffusion of

an item as for example, the better quality varieties of pottery in archaeological

evidence. The distribution of the Northern Black Polished Ware—a luxury

ceramic—is an indicator of places in contact with each other. Such an exchange

provides evidence not only on local trade but also on the geographical reach of

intra-regional contacts. Some of these settlements may then have come to play

the role of local markets, the equivalent perhaps of what the Pali texts refer to as

the nigama. These in turn are likely to have been the nuclei of urban growth as in

the case of towns such as Rajagriha and Sravasti in the middle Ganga plain.

Distinct from all these is the familiar picture of trade which dominates the

scene in the post-Mauryan period. This is the commercial exchange between two

or more centres processing and producing commodities specifically destined for

trade. The organization of this more complex form involved a hierarchy of

producers and traders some of whom were sedentary while others were carriers

of the items traded but of a different order from pedlars and pastoralists. The

picture of commercialized exchange emerges from Buddhist texts. Some monks

were also involved in brade. The Arthashastra regards it as a legitimate source

of revenue for the State. The question then arose of the degree of State

interference and control that would be conducive to increasing the finances of

the State.

The major artefact in this trade (other than the commodities) was coined

metallic money, providing evidence of the degree of complexity and the extent

of such trade and trading circuits. These early coins in some instances were

issued by the nigama and in other cases may have been issued by local

authorities or possibly by ruling families. In the post-Mauryan period dynastic

issues gained currency, a clear pointer to the importance of commercialized

exchange. However, even in this period local issues remained in circulation

suggesting multiple levels of exchange.

Given these commercial activities, the control of trade routes becomes a


significant factor in political policy and military annexations. Recent analyses of

activities along the Silk Route linking China to the eastern Mediterranean via

Central Asia have revealed a variety of levels of exchange. These ranged from

gift-exchange to sophisticated emporia, in the context of political relations

between tribal groups and established centres of political power, suggesting

ways in which the complicated question of trade, often treated as a uniform

monolith by historians of early India, may now be investigated. The Roman

trade with India, as is clear from both commodities and the function of money,

also spans a similar range. Diverse forms of exchange within a larger trading

system suggest the coexistence of various economic levels within that system

and sharpen the social contours of the groups involved.

Analyzing trade also requires locating those involved in these exchanges in

the social hierarchy of the time. In the production of goods for exchange,

artisans, whether individuals or in guilds, had relationships with merchants and

financiers that were as diverse in form as the various categories of relationships

and tenancies between cultivators and landowners. The role of the shilpin

(artisan) and the shreni (guild) is quite distinct from the setthi. Their presence

registers a change in the nature of the trade as does the differentiation between

categories of professionals, such as the vanija (merchant), setthi (financier and

merchant), and the sarthavaha, (caravaneer).

When commercialized exchange becomes active it introduces a substantial

change. The investment required for elaborate trade had to be provided by a

well-endowed group able to invest its surplus in risk-taking ventures. The

obvious category was the gahapati who could fall back on land if the venture

failed. That it turned out to be highly successful is clear from the fact that not


only did the setthis emerge from the ranks of the gahapatis, but, by the post-

Mauryan period, had an independent identity as financiers and gradually


superceded the gahapatis.

As a result of the wealth they accumulated the setthis came to be powerful,

for some of them were known to be financiers of kings and obtained in return

rights to collect revenue, perhaps the prototype of what was later to become the

regular form of emoluments to administrative officers. On the manifestations of

trade, Buddhist and Jaina sources together with epigraphic and archaeological

evidence provide a useful counterpoint to the conventional Dharmashastra

literature of this period.

The link between agriculture and commerce is important for understanding

the changes in the subsequent period. The opulence of those involved in

commerce was poured into the adornment of religious monuments, monasteries


and images and in the conspicuous consumption that is associated with the

wealthier town-dwellers of these times. This tends to obscure the agrarian scene

where one notices less of wealthy landowners and large estates and more of

those with small holdings.

Small plots of land could be purchased and donated to religious beneficiaries

and it seems unlikely, as has been argued, that such sales were restricted to

religious donations. Small holdings together with the alienation of land could

point to some degree of impoverishment among peasants. References to debt

bondage (ahitaka, atmavikreta), as a regular if not frequent category of slavery,

as well as the increasing references to vishti (forced labour or a labour tax),

suggest a different rural scene from that of the preceding period. Oppressive

taxation—referred to as pain-causing taxation—is mentioned as an evil.

This mutation was endemic to the evident change in the post-Gupta period.

Where trade flourished, the resources of the urban centres and the trade routes

bouyed up the system: but this period points to a declining trade in some areas.

Internal commercialized trade requires the ballast of agrarian settlements and

where lineage-based societies could be converted into peasant economies, the

agrarian support to trade would be strengthened.

Earlier networks of exchange had permitted an easier coexistence with

lineage-based societies. Their resources, generally raw materials such as

elephants, timber and gemstones could, as items of exchange, be easily tapped

by traders through barter and direct exchange without disturbing the social

structure to any appreciable degree. On the other hand, because of the

requirement of land and labour, state systems more heavily dependent on a

peasant economy had to absorb these societies and convert them into peasant

economies in order to extract the benefits.

Where trade declined or where new states were established, the need to

develop the agrarian economy became necessary. The granting of land appears to

have been the mechanism adopted for extending areas under cultivation. The

reasons for this change in the post-Gupta period need more detailed

investigation, particularly at a regional level. In the very useful work done so far,

substantial data has surfaced. What is now required is a sifting and classifying of

the data to provide more precise answers and to evoke fresh questions.

The kind of data required is that which would provide information on basic

questions relating to agrarian relations. A comparative regional view would be

useful. Grants could be classified in terms of type and area, the nature of the land

and soil, the crops grown, local irrigation, degrees of ownership and tenancy, and

who provided labour. A worm’s eye view of agriculture could be better handled


through inter-disciplinary research. Historians could work with soil specialists

and hydrologists. The absence of field studies is unfortunate. Although it has

entered into some discussions of archaeological sites it is absent among

historians. An increase in data of the technical kind can assist the quality of

theoretical analyses. Many of these questions could involve extrapolating from

existing records but the more valuable input would come from fieldwork in the

area under study. It is not for nothing that R.H. Tawney, who wrote on the

economic history of Europe, is believed to have said that the first essential of

research into agrarian history is a stout pair of boots.

At another level, the analyses of the titles of grantees and changes therein

might provide clues. The question of whether the peasantry was free hinges not

only on the technical and legal definitions but also requires a discussion of the

actual status of the peasant. Rights, obligations and dues of the grantees vis-à-vis

the peasants would need to be tabulated in detail. These would provide some

indications of the essentials of the prevailing system.

It is curious that there is little resort to the policy recommended by the

Arthashastra of establishing colonies of cultivators on land owned by the state,

so as to extend agriculture and thereby increase the revenue. Was the state

unable to do so because it lacked the administrative infrastructure, or was it

because it did not have the power to implement such a policy? Or had the

economy changed to the point of discouraging the feasibility of such a policy?

Instead, the state increased the grants of land to religious beneficiaries and later,

but to a lesser extent, to administrative officers in lieu of a salary. This points to

a need for an evaluation of the nature of the states of this period with the

possibility that their formation and structure were different from the previous

ones.

Was this type of state attempting to restructure the economy to a greater

extent than the previous ones that may have been more concerned with revenue

collecting—judging by the model advocated by Kautilya? Did the system of

granting land predominate (perhaps initially) in areas where lineage-based

societies were prevalent so as to facilitate their conversion to a peasant economy

and where lineage could also be used for economic control? More than varna

identities, jati identities would have acted as a bridge to a peasant economy and

ameliorated the rupture with the lineage system. Elements of lineage have often

continued even in some areas where peasant agriculture became the norm.

Religious benefices were on the pattern of earlier grants and were not strictly

an innovation except that now grants were made increasingly to brahmanas and

ostensibly in return for legitimizing the dynasty and for the donor acquiring


religious merit. These were the stated reasons for the grant but were not

sufficient reasons. Grants of this nature, as has been pointed out, were a channel

of acculturation. They could also be used as foci of political loyalty.

If the grants were made initially from state-owned lands, they amounted to a

renouncing of revenue. If the state was unable to administer the extension of

agriculture, was the system of grants also introduced to encourage settlements in

new areas where the grant was of waste land, or alternatively, of cultivated lands

to stabilize the peasantry and induce increased production? Given the fact that

slaves were not used in any quantitative degree in agricultural production at this

time, was the system of grants an attempt at converting the peasantry into a

stable productive force through various mechanisms of subordination and a

chain of intermediaries?

Interestingly, the term gahapati/grihapati drops out of currency, for the system

had changed and terms incorporating raja, samanta and bhogin, become

frequent. Samanta had originally been the word used for a neighbour. The

meaning now changed and it referred to a grantee who had received land.

Bhogin was the one who enjoyed the produce of the land. The recipients of land

grants had the right to receive a range of taxes and dues previously collected by

the state and were soon given administrative and (some) judicial powers. This

permitted them to act us a ‘backup’ administration where the grant was in settled

areas and to introduce the system where new settlements were being established.

It may in origin have been a fiscal measure but in effect became the means of

controlling the peasantry.

The apparent increase in debt bondage and the fear of peasant migration

would point to this being one of the functions of the large-scale grants. That the

possibility of peasant migration to alleviate discontent was being slowly stifled

is suggested by the fact of peasants possibly taking to revolt from the early

second millennium onwards. A rise in brigandage may well have occurred in this

period judging by the increase in hero-stones in some areas. These were

memorials to local heroes who had died defending the village and its cattle. A

qualitative change occurs when the state begins to grant villages or substantial

acreages of land already under cultivation: a change that reflects both on the

economy and on the nature of the state.

The need to fetter the peasantry would seem an evident departure from the

earlier system and this in turn introduced a change in the relationship between

the cultivator and the land now riveted in legalities and liabilities, with tax or

rent no longer being the sole criterion of a peasant economy. The karshaka of

this period found himself in a different situation from the kassaka of earlier


times. The term ‘peasant’ therefore cannot have a blanket usage or meaning

since the variations within it have to be distinguished.

The secular grantees were part of an hierarchical system in which they

mirrored the court at the local level. This is evident from their attempts to imitate

the courtly style as depicted in the art and literature of the time. Grants of land to

the brahmanas as the major religious grantees rehabilitated them to a position of

authority and their anguished invocation of Kalki as a millennial figure became

less urgent. The codes of caste were, seemingly at least, not being overturned as

vigorously as had been feared in earlier times. It is more likely that the forms

were outwardly adhered to and the matter seemed to end at that point, without

too much investigation into the mobility of jatis.

A new religious ideology gained popularity. It focused on the icon and the

temple and asserted an assimilative quality involving the cults and rituals of

Puranic Hinduism and the genesis of the Bhakti tradition. Ideological

assimilation is called for when there is a need to knit together socially diverse

groups. It is also crucial when there is an increase in the distancing between such

groups as well as the power of some over others and the economic disparity

between them.

The significance of these new cults and sects may lie in part in the focus on

loyalty to a deity that has parallels to the loyalty of peasants and others to an

overlord. But it would be worth examining the rudiments of each sect in its

regional dimension, its groping towards a jati status and the use of an ostensibly

cultural and religious idiom to express a new social identity. Were these also

mechanisms for legitimizing territorial identities, drawing on sacred geography

and pilgrimage routes, with the temple as the focal point?

The devotees were emphasizing what they perceived to be their equal status

as devotees in the eyes of the deity. Can this be viewed as the assertion of those

lower down the social scale in favour of a more egalitarian society? But its

significance grows when the social background to this belief is one of increasing

disparity. Movements of dissent that acquired religious legitimacy and form were

often gradually accommodated and their radical content slowly diluted. The

move away from community participation in a ritual to a personalized and

private worship encourages the notion of individual freedom, even if it is only at

the ideological level. The Vedic sacrificial ritual was a gathering of the clan,

whereas forms of worship like Bhakti can be entirely based on how the

individual sees his or her relationship with the deity.

In the justifiable emphasis on social and economic history there has been too

frequently neglect among historians of the analysis of ideology. To study


ideology without its historical context is to practice historical hydroponics, for

ideas and beliefs strike roots in the humus of historical reality. To restrict the

study of a society to its narrowly social and economic forms alone is to see it in

a limited two-dimensional profile. The interaction of society and ideology takes

a varied pattern and to insist always on the primacy of the one over the other is

to deny the richness of a full-bodied historical explanation.

Ideas are sometimes analyzed as a response to social pressures and needs.

This is particularly pertinent for those dealing with social history. Some of the

more important literature (of the times) is suffused with a theoretical

representation of society even in symbolic or ideational forms. Meanings very

often do not stem from just the vocabulary but require familiarity with the

cultural context of the word. Examples of this would be the levels of meaning in

words such a varna and jati as they travel through time in texts such as the

Dharmashastras. The ideological layers in the latter as codes of behaviour have

to be peeled away in order to obtain a better comprehension of their ordering of

society.

Central to any concern with ideology in the ancient past is the critique of

religious thought, as distinct from religious practice or the organization of

religious institutions. Some analyses of the Upanishads for instance, can provide

an interesting example of this. One of the major strands in Upanishadic thought

is said to be a secret doctrine known only to a few kshatriyas who teach it to

select, trusted brahmanas. Even the most learned among the latter, the mahashala

mahashrotriya are described as going to the kshatriyas for instruction. This does

rather reverse the code but it seems not to have mattered in this context. The

doctrine they discuss involves the idea of the soul, the atman and its ultimate

merging with the universal soul, the brahman as well as metempsychosis and the

transmigration of the soul: in fact a fundamental doctrine of this age which was

to have far-reaching consequences on Indian society.

That it should have been secret and originally associated with the kshatriyas

raises many questions, some of which have been discussed by scholars. It is true

that the brahmanas and the kshatriyas were both members of the ‘leisured

classes’ in Vedic society and could therefore indulge in idealistic philosophy and

discourse on the niceties of life after death. But this is only a partial answer and

much more remains to be explained. Was the ritual of sacrifice so deeply

imprinted on the brahmana mind and so necessary to the profession at this point,

that it required non-brahmanas to introduce alternatives to moksha, the liberation

of the soul from rebirth, other than the sacrificial ritual? The adoption of

meditation and theories of transmigration had the advantage of releasing the


kshatriyas from the pressures of a prestation economy, permitting them to

accumulate wealth, which in turn gave them access to power and leisure.

Alternatively, was the accumulation of these already present in the fringe

areas described as the mleccha-desha (impure lands) in Vedic texts, where the

sacrificial rituals for various reasons had become less important? Thus Janaka of

Mithila, Ashvapati Kaikeya and Ajatashatru of Kashi could reflect on alternative

ways to moksha, other than the ritual of sacrifice. This also places a different

emphasis on the function of the kshatriya who had now ceased to be primarily a

cattle-raiding, warrior chief.

These are not the only kinds of connections relevant to a history of the period.

Upper and lower caste groups treated as monolithic, belie social reality. The

tensions within these should also be noticed where the evidence suggests this.

The competition for status between brahmanas and kshatriyas and the separation

of their functions, although retaining their mutual dependence, is symbolized in

the sacrificial ritual that becomes a key articulation of the relationship. The new

beliefs discussed in the Upanishads reversed up to a point the sacrificial ritual, in

that they required neither priests nor deities but only self-discipline and

meditation. At another level, the transmigrating of the soul through the natural

elements and plants to its ultimate rebirth carries an echo of shamanism which

may have remained popular outside priestly ritual.

There is in the new belief the first element of a shift from the clan to the

individual in as much as the sacrificial ritual involves the clan and its wealth, but

meditation and self-discipline, in opposition to the clan, involves only the

individual. It symbolizes the breaking away of the individual from the clan. It

also introduces an element of anomie that becomes more apparent in the later

development of these beliefs by various sects. These reflections were seminal to

what became a major direction in Indian thought and action, the opting out of the

individual from society, where renunciation is a method of self-discovery, but

can also carry a message of dissent.

That the new ideas were attributed to the kshatriyas and yet included in a

brahmanical text was probably because for the brahmanas to author a doctrine

openly questioning the sacrificial ritual would, at this stage, have been an

anomaly. However for kshatriyas wanting to be released from expending their

wealth in yajanas, an alternate to the sacrificial ritual was a potentially important

departure. That the doctrine stimulated philosophical discussion would in itself

have required that it be recorded. Additionally, since some teachings of the

heterodox reflected aspects of this doctrine, by setting it out as an important part

of the Vedic corpus, it could be claimed that even the heterodox had ultimately


to uphold aspects of the Vedic tradition. Such an argument is made many

centuries later, in modern times. This assumes that the Upanishadic doctrine

preceded the heterodox teachings, but it may have been the reverse.

This was to become yet another technique by which orthodox theory in

subsequent centuries sought to disguise ideas contradicting its own position. The

Buddha not only democratized the doctrine but also nurtured the idea of karma

and samsara, actions in this life determining the quality of rebirth in the next, a

generally held belief that explained social inequities. For him the link was

through consciousness as he denied the existence of the soul. But his negation of

the soul (atman) introduces a contradiction of the doctrine as visualized in the

Upanishads. Such contradictions were current at that time. The positing of a

thesis and an anti-thesis prior to arriving at a possible synthesis, became a

characteristic feature of philosophical debate and was reflected both in empirical

disciplines such as grammar as well as in more abstract analysis.

The relating of ideology to historical reality, as historians are now doing, can

result not only in new ways of examining an historical situation and be used to

extend or modify the analysis from other sources, but can also help in

confirming the reality as derived from other sources.

Such a study, incorporating elements of the deconstruction of both material

culture and ideas, would sharpen the awareness of concepts and theoretical

frameworks. Historical explanation then becomes an enterprise in which the

nuances and refinements of concepts and theories are a constant necessity, not

only because of the availability of fresh evidence from new sources but also

because of greater precision in our understanding of the categories which we use

to analyze these sources.

No comments:

Post a Comment